• Skip to primary navigation
  • Skip to main content
  • Skip to primary sidebar

From the Government

How Governments Have Made Us Healthier, Wealthier, and Better Educated and Made Our Lives Safer and Fairer

How Governments Have Made Us
Healthier, Wealthier, and Better Educated
and Made Our Lives Safer and Fairer

  • About
  • Archive
  • Contact
You are here: Home / Federal government / Public Transit

Public Transit

November 1, 2020 by Otis 5 Comments

Few alive today can remember, but public transit (subways, commuter rail, buses, streetcars, and ferries) was once a for-profit industry. So how did nearly all of these services end up under government ownership? Because, at a point, private owners walked away from them. Cities, regional authorities, and states stepped in to keep the services alive and, in many cases, expand them.

So this is the story of one of government’s strengths: its steadfastness. Once it recognizes a vital service, it doesn’t give up on it as easily as corporations. We’ll get into why transit is considered vital to cities but, first, a little history.

Transit in America began in the early 1800s with ferry boats and horse-drawn wagons called omnibuses. For a price, these private services would take passengers across a river or across town on a fixed route—like modern-day buses and streetcars. But an omnibus ride was a bumpy one since most streets were either dirt or cobblestones. Before the Civil War, then, to smooth the ride, some private companies laid down rails on the streets for the wagons to use. For this, they needed government approval, since cities owned the streets. This was the point when government first played a role in transit, as granters of rights of way.

It wasn’t until engineers figured out how to use electricity as a means of locomotion, though, that the “mass” part of mass transit took off. Electricity allowed private companies to build efficient streetcars and, later, elevated trains and subways that could move large numbers at small, “token” prices.

As transit grew, so did congestion. By the early 1900s, city streets had become a jumble of transportation modes. There were streetcars, pedestrians, bicyclists, horse-drawn wagons, and a few privately owned cars, all fighting for a piece of the pavement. (For a glimpse, watch this video of New York in 1911, starting at the 1:28 mark.) That’s why the transit companies wanted exclusive right of ways, either above the street (in elevated trains) or below (in subways).

This got some of the transit out of public streets, but the tunnels and elevated tracks required even greater government cooperation. New York’s subways, for instance, were mostly “cut and cover” projects. That is, streets were dug up, tunnels and tracks built, then the streets were covered again. In most cities, the construction was privately financed but the city had to give its permission to close the streets and its elected officials felt the anger of residents and businesses that were disrupted.

So here was another way government became a major player in mass transit, as a partner in its construction. There was yet another role it came to play: regulator of fares. Why? Because, in nearly every case, the transit companies were monopoly businesses. And in return for the monopoly status—and the city’s help with construction—local governments gained a say in transit fares, much as state public service commissions set electric and natural gas rates today. It was another step toward government involvement.

Why did the private companies leave the business? Because it became less profitable as cars pushed their way into cities. Transit ridership peaked in 1926, then began a steady decline as more people drove to work or shopping. And as profits declined, so did maintenance, which encouraged yet more people to abandon buses and trains for private automobiles.

In the 1940s and 1950s, one city government after another bought out the private companies and took over their train and bus lines. The best that cities could do, at first, was maintain the systems they had bought, and without expansion or improvements, ridership continued its decline.

What changed things in the 1960s and 1970s was that the federal government started financing transit. This led to brand-new rapid transit systems in Washington, D.C., San Francisco-Oakland, and Atlanta, and expansions and renovations for older systems like those in Boston and Chicago.

By the early years of the 21st century, transit ridership was rising again. Then, in about 2010, ridership hit a wall. There were a number of reasons. In places like New York and Washington, D.C., transit systems had deferred maintenance to the point that service suffered. And as trains became overcrowded and undependable, riders looked for alternatives—and found it in new transportation services, like Uber and Lyft.

Better management was beginning to turn around big-city transit systems when, in 2020, ridership fell off a cliff with the Covid-19 pandemic and the public health shutdown that followed. It is unclear when or how ridership will improve. Still, no major American city signaled an intention to give up on transit.

Why are local governments so committed to public transit? Because transit has important positive externalities: It makes cities more affordable. It reduces pollution. It creates denser development, which makes streets livelier. And it leads to more productive land uses by reducing one of the most wasteful uses, which is parking. (To see how transit can change land uses, compare San Francisco’s two baseball parks, the old Candlestick Park, remote and surrounded by parking, and the new Oracle Park, with transit at its doorstep.)

If you’ve ever taken a train or bus in a city—or merely appreciated the liveliness of urban streets—you can thank government for maintaining the transit systems that make these possible.

More information:

https://oxfordre.com/americanhistory/view/10.1093/acrefore/9780199329175.001.0001/acrefore-9780199329175-e-28

https://www.britannica.com/topic/mass-transit/The-benefits-of-urban-mass-transit

Give the credit to: local governments 70%, federal government 30%

Filed Under: Federal government, Federalism, Great Society, Local governments, Urbanism Tagged With: 1964-72, Externalities, Fairer, Late 1800s, Transportation, Wealthier

Reader Interactions

Trackbacks

  1. Farmers Markets | From the Government says:
    December 19, 2020 at 5:10 pm

    […] and enjoyable. These are positive externalities, a concept we’ve written about in our entries on public transit and building codes and […]

    Reply
  2. Cleaner Air and Cleaner Water | From the Government says:
    February 21, 2021 at 6:09 pm

    […] externalities,” which are benefits produced indirectly by the service. Examples are public transit, farmers markets, and sidewalks and trails. Pollution is the classic example of a “negative […]

    Reply
  3. The Census | From the Government says:
    March 6, 2021 at 10:48 pm

    […] we saw in earlier entries, some of the things we associate today with government—public transit, clean drinking water, waste disposal and public sanitation, public schools, police and public […]

    Reply
  4. The Internet | From the Government says:
    March 27, 2021 at 7:01 pm

    […] but ended up in the public because governments could do the work cheaper and better, things like public transit, public schools, and fire safety and prevention. Now, let’s turn to something that began as a […]

    Reply
  5. Appliance Energy Standards | From the Government says:
    December 5, 2023 at 2:29 pm

    […] we’ve talked about in earlier entries about farmers markets, building codes and inspections, and public transit.) So, have these efforts reduced the amount of energy we […]

    Reply

Leave a Reply to Cleaner Air and Cleaner Water | From the Government Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Primary Sidebar

Categories

Tags

1930s 1964-72 Better educated Children Cities Civil War Collaboration Economic development Education Elderly Energy Externalities Fairer Franklin Roosevelt Germ theory Health care Healthier Higher education Home ownership Late 1800s Lyndon Johnson Market failure National defense Parks Public health Public safety Public schools Public works Race to the Bottom Safer Tourism Transportation Wealthier

Recent Posts

  • Farmers Markets
  • Patents, Copyrights, and Trademarks
  • The Postal Service
  • Consumer Product Safety
  • Workplace Safety
  • Dependable Insurance
  • Food and Drug Safety
  • Professional Licenses
  • Public Television and Radio
  • The Internet
  • Cooperative Extension
  • Weather Forecasts and Storm Warnings
  • The Census
  • Cleaner Air and Cleaner Water
  • Appliance Energy Standards
  • Minimum Wage
  • Unemployment Insurance
  • Human Genome Project
  • Sidewalks and Trails
  • Disaster Relief
  • Americans with Disabilities Act
  • Civil Rights and Voting Rights
  • Vocational Education
  • Public Libraries
  • Building Codes and Inspections
  • Elevator Inspections
  • National Defense
  • Driver’s Licenses
  • Public Transit
  • Streets and Roads
  • Honest Markets and Sound Banks
  • Rural Electrification and Rural Broadband
  • Interstate Transportation
  • Medicare
  • Social Security
  • Playgrounds and Recreation
  • Public Hospitals
  • Public Schools
  • The Courts
  • Police and Public Safety
  • Fire Safety and Prevention
  • Clean Drinking Water
  • Nuclear Safety and Nuclear Waste Disposal
  • Public Health and Disease Control
  • State and National Parks
  • City Parks
  • Waste Disposal and Public Sanitation
  • State Colleges and Universities
  • 30-Year Mortgage

Copyright © 2025 · Log in